Ideal Money and the Motivation of Savings and Thrift
I have been talking, at meetings, about my ideas on the topic of Ideal Money for a few years now while the world,
by coincidence, has passed through and into some financial/economic crises
that have been quite interrelated to the systems or varieties of money that have been recently in use.
For example, most recently, the difficulties that derived from the national debt of Greece,
which is currently defined in terms of euros whereas it had been, earlier, defined in terms of drachmas;
these difficulties have led to extreme” bail out” actions and to global fears and reactions.
And earlier the “panic of 2008”, which was quite severe and somehow very reminiscent of the American “panic of 1907”,
seemed to derive from causal factors in the USA which linked with the traditional array of efforts
provided by federal support and/or subsidies for the building a single-family homes.
So there, somehow, came into being a flood of “sub-prime mortgages” which led to floods
of “derivatives” which were, unjustifiably, advertised as being of high “investment grade”).
Honesty is the Best Policy
When I spoke at an economics meeting in Tampa, Florida, in 2001, on the topic of “Ideal Money”.
I suggested the use of an “ICPI” index for the definition of the proper value for an “ideal” money.
Here ICPI stood for “Industrial Consumption Price Index”
for these industrial commodities which of course could be precious metals).
But I did not have any specific proposals, like prices for copper, or platinum, or electric energy to suggest for the index.
Now, after some years of thought and observations,
I feel that the sort of authority or agency that would be able to establish any version of ideal money
who have provided practical media for use in traders’ exchanges.
We can prepare to appropriately respect the functioning of such an agency (conceivably like the IMF or BIS or ECB)
and concede to the effective agency some discretion about the specific form of a guiding index of prices.
But here is where I see the importance of honesty,
as if like the honesty of a well-regarded classical European monarch or emperor.
Sometimes the people in the USA have been told things like “inflation is not a problem”
when statistics compiled by the Labor Department (following “classical” rules) indicate that there is, indeed, ongoing inflation.
If an appropriately honest government-like agency is to issue the actual currency,
and to provide for the central bank deposits denominated in terms of that currency, for a money system, then it
can also, naturally, compute the indexes that would measure the presence or absence of inflation or deflation.
My position is that the appropriate “target rate” for measured inflation is zero.
In recent times, after the unsurprising breakdown of the IMF-sponsored system of fixed exchange rates,
there have been globally varying patterns of inflation linked to the varying national or regional currencies.
If the Canadian money unit is “targeted” for 2% inflation and if it gains in value compared with the unit of the USA
then this suggests that the actual recent inflation rate for the currency of the USA is at least 2%.
My natural presumption is that the authorities responsible for national currencies,
during this time period (since 1971) have effectively calculated their strategies on a basis of how respectable
in comparison to other national paper fiat monies and in comparison to the US dollar.
Gresham’s law, Gresham was sort of a contemporary of Queen Elizabeth I and his law was a
What happens is that there are different quality levels of money circulating.
The better quality is hoarded and that which is lower quality is passed on.
So, well, it’s pragmatically true.
My natural presumption is that the authorities are responsible.
Some History of Institutions Created to Promote Savings by Individual Savers
The first case opposed to a savings bank was established in the UK in 1861 paying interest at 2.5%.
In the USA a comparable system was established in 1911 but was discontinued in 1966
When visiting Shenzhen in China recently as a tourist,
I was surprised to see a “Postal Savings Bank” in existence there and the name was in English as well as Chinese.
And I later learned that at this time the largest such national system is that in Japan.
The “Savings and Loan Associations”, or the variously named institutions with analogous descriptive names,
originated in the UK in the midst of the era of “strong money”, when the British pound was on the “Newtonian” gold standard.
That jargon from Isaac Newton having been master of the mint
at the time of the standardisation of the ratio between the pounds unit and actual gold.
Around 1770 the comparable savings institutions in the UK were those called “building societies”.
Earlier in their modern history the “savings and loan associations” in the US had a separate insurance corporation
established to protect their depositors which was the FSLIC or Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation
and which was directly parallel to the FDIC corporation which insured deposit account balances in ordinary “commercial banks”.
But when the great tide of inflation flowed in from Washington’s definitive break (in 1971) with providing,
for the IMF member states, a gold quota for the dollar, and with various cases of corruption in the S.& L. area
that arose derived from relaxation of earlier versions of strong regulatory standards,
the result ultimately was that the FSLIC (which had borne the great weight of bailouts) was simply abolished
and all of its remaining insureds were put under the umbrella of the FDIC
besides of its main function of insuring small or modest sized deposit accounts in retail commercial banks)).
Before being effectively terminated, the “S&L’s” in the USA were perhaps comparable to “Icesave”
and that comparison suggests also how their investments may have had weaknesses with regard to risk probabilities.
So, under extreme variations in the general economic/financial climate, they were not able to survive
Conditions for the Attractiveness of Savings Accounts
An individual of the species “homo oeconomicus”, blessed, we presume, with the facility of “rational expectations”,
can be imagined in the situation of needing to decide on whether to put money into a “savings account”
or perhaps to follow some other strategy with his money, over a period of time.
It is not widely advertised by American financial or banking institutions,
but the rate of interest that they would pay on deposit or “money market” accounts
might be lower than the rational expectation for the rate of inflation relevant for the national currency.
So should the “economic person” rationally decide to “save”, using such a channel for the depositing of his money, or, perhaps,
should that person decide to go early into a housing purchase for which he/she might need to borrow money,
perhaps under the conditions applicable to “sub-prime borrowers”.
It is obviously not simply “thrifty”, but under conditions of uncertainty about the continuing value of the national currency
it could, indeed, be the more rational choice to go earlier into the house purchase
rather than to wait to develop a stronger basis, by saving money over a time period,
before reaching the time to make a “down payment” on a mortgage financed house purchase.
But under the conditions generally obtaining, for the US dollar and for the British pound, at the time period,
say, of 1870 through 1910, there were modest interest rates available for savers
or in other institutions offering comparable deposit accounts AND this in the context of the general absence of inflation
because of the dollar and the pound then both standing in a standardized fixed price relationship to the “troy ounce” of gold).
But of course we can note that in those days,
although depositors could earn a genuine increment of interest on their savings deposits,
there was generally no provision for an insurance coverage for the possibility, like recently with “Icesave”,
that the calculations of the institution might not be perfectly far-seeing.
It was, perhaps, a time when one needed to know something, effectively,
about both the moral character and the financial wisdom of one’s banker.
It seems that there have been times, historically, when there would be “good bankers”, like maybe a Rothschild, or a Morgan,
or a Giannini, and recently or now we seem, comparatively, to have been in the era of bank executives who win, as players,
if their employer does not fail during their time as employees, and lose, as players,
if the bank fails and is absorbed through something like the American FDIC, but then do not really LOSE BIG
Contracts and Justice
In Game Theory there is generally the concept of “payoffs”, if the game is not simply a game
of win or lose (or win, lose, or draw).
The game may be concerned with actions all to be taken like at the same time
so that the utility measure for defining the payoffs could be taken to be any practical currency with good divisibility
and measurability properties at the relevant instant of time.
But also there can be quite analogous game situations
with the time for the game actions extending over, comparatively, a long period of time.
In the USA there is frequently news about a basketball player (or another variety of professional athlete)
who is signing on typically assisted by an agent)
to serve for a period of some years on the athletic team “owned” by some sports entrepreneur.
The interesting thing is that,
as the time period for all the performances of the athletic services contract becomes more extended,
the contract becomes more comparable to mortgage loan contracts in relation to how the quality of the currency unit
of the terms of the contract will relate to the demands expressed in the contract.
In the area of mortgages the phenomenon of the uncertainty about the amount of inflation to be expected
has led to various adaptations, for example the frequent use of “ARM” mortgages
where the interest rate collected varies with the current pattern of interest rates in some market.
So we can see that, for contracts relevant to the studies, in particular, of a school or department of “Business Administration”,
it is as if there is another player in the game of the contract signers and this player is the Sovereign
who provides the medium of currency
in terms of which the contract is to be expressed.
Well, my basic point is simply that as the currency of the Sovereign tends to have less stability
and less reliability of its value
then the circumstances affecting the formation of business-relevant contracts become quite perturbed.
It seems that inflation affecting currencies is GENERALLY or NORMALLY with some associated unpredictability,
although it would be POSSIBLE, for example, for the Swedish krona to have a 1% “targeted” inflation rate
in terms of comparison with the Swiss franc although this is NOT what we would rationally expect,
because of various political and other considerations.
My recommendation to economists generally and to planners
who may influence the economic and business rules operating within or among states is to consider the value of economic and
business conditions where it is possible to deal well with longer term contracts.
Such contracts, for example, have notably been of use in the past with public works projects.
National Money and Provincial Money
If the money used in the central capital areas of a nation is also used in the provinces
and if the provinces also have governments and local taxes then the quality of the money ordained
by the Sovereign on the national level will affect the conditions for trade and investment, etc. in any province.
For example we could think of the UK and of Scotland as the province.
If, say, a Scot named Adam Smith has a temporary surplus of earned income over expenses
then what can he do with this surplus that is both cautious and wise.
Mr. Smith must logically have some concern over the conjectural probabilities regarding the value of the currency he would use
which we can presume to have the same value per unit as that used in London.
In Switzerland the analogous provinces are the “cantons”.
And these cantons typically may have a cantonal bank which is, in a sense, comparable to an office of a postal savings system.
But each cantonal bank is under local control and administration.
A depositor in such a provincial bank MIGHT be able to save a little money
with a modest level of efficiency,
but ONLY if the characteristics of the money standard which is used to define his/her account are favorable.
Thus we can see how the cantons of Switzerland themselves, as economic entities, have an interest in the qualities of the exchange medium that is provided by the Sovereign (Confederation).
And similarly in Edinburgh there is the possibility of locally founded concerns about the pound.
In relation to these considerations I suggest that, in general, if the money that must be used
by a set of provinces of an aggregative state is of a comparatively higher level of quality
then that this circumstance can favor decisions in the provinces in favor of more thrifty options or alternatives.
The provinces themselves may have savings accounts, like if some bond issue has been issued by an American state,
then this may run over a period of time.
The state has that time to pay off, according to specified terms in relation to dollars.
It could be a very, very good deal and sometimes you would think because sometimes those rates are very low.
Contractual Reliability as a Pattern of Culture
There have often been attempts by various students of history or writers on Economics
to link times and places of good economic progress to cultural circumstances
that might be imagined to favor, somehow, the good fortune.
If this sort of thing were really well understood then it should be taught in schools of “Business Administration”.
We can see, however, that there is an option which can be taken
or partially taken to improve the metrical reliability of contracts.
For example imagine two parties in Zimbabwe wishing to arrange for one of them
to sell the rights to a patent to the other when the patent will be valid for 15 years into the future.
On a cash basis the issue is simple, comparatively, and if it was that the Zimbabwe dollar was in use there
then they could have used that for the cash transaction.
But the patent might be worth considerably more
if the payment for it could be stretched out over the 15 years remaining of its validity.
However, if a contract were to be written involving payment for the patent in installments
then the seller would logically wish to consider the prospects,
over the period of 15 years into the future, of the value of the Zimbabwe dollar.
But can this be scientifically or objectively calculated.
My point is simply that good reliability of the estimates of the future value of a currency, a “medium of exchange”,
is favorable for the formation of contracts of a business-related variety.
And the general pattern, within a State or a zone of legal customs and rules,
becomes effectively a part of the business culture there and we can see that, other things being equal,
a more favorable “business culture” should be expected, at least as long as we remain dependent on “private enterprise”
and on entrepreneurs, if only on a partial scale, to enhance economic progress
and the effective value of the products produced within the State or zone.
Investment Banking and the Quality of a Local Currency
It can be observed, for example, that the income acquired as wages through the labor of workers working,
perhaps, in the “City of London”, in the area of “investment banking”
contributes a disproportionate part of the total income coming into the UK as part of the “gross national product” of the UK.
Some of these workers may be “quants” who are actually mathematicians working similarly to actuaries.
Now the activities of all the banks and financial and related enterprises there in the City
or in London naturally interact with the characteristics of the currency used.
Of course the London office of J.P. Morgan Chase, for example,
may do most of its transactions on other bases than in terms of pounds.
But the comparative quality and stability of the pound
will naturally affect the attitudes of all the participants in the financial businesses there.
We can observe also that the prominence, in areas of finance, of London, is not a recent development in time
but that it goes back, in time, to when the Empire was still a successful and profitable enterprise
and when the pound had become the Number One currency of the world
Now at this time, in 2011,
it seems to me that some other centers might desire to get into this sort of profitable employment of human labor.
In particular the possibility of centers like Tokyo, Shanghai, Kuala Lumpur, Beirut, and Sao Paulo comes to mind.
And in each case the quality (in a sense like that of Gresham in Gresham’s Law)
of the locally employed currency will favor or disfavor the prospects
for the growth of a local center for financial activities including “investment banking”.
So this is the end of my text.